Paying College Players? The Proposal - Volume 1
When a collegiate sporting event takes place different
people ask different questions. The mother of the star play might ask, "is my Baby going to get
hurt?"
The teacher of the star player might ask, I wonder, "did he get that
homework done?"
The coach might ask, "is he going to come
through?"
The local beer company that sponsors the telecast is asking,
"did we get good media exposure from this game?"
The University Chancellor might ask, "How many prospective
students are we going to get out of this telecast?"
The lowly Economist (yeah, that’s me) asks, "How much
extra value did this star player earn for everyone involved?”
The truth is that when
NCAA college contracts were originally created, video games did not
exist, videotaping was evolving from film and the internet was an imaginary
concept. Technology has allowed players to provide
entertainment to a world wide audience so that athletic feats get played over
and over on cable television, in video games, on laptops and PDAs across
America. The college player of 2015 will
generate revenue for years and years to come with one performance.
If that same college player walks into a music studio and
creates a hit song as a singer, he or she receives worldwide rights and
revenues. If that same college player
walks into a movie studio and creates a hit film as an actor, he or she
receives worldwide rights and revenues.
Similarly, once that same college player walks into the professional
ranks of their sport, they receive revenues.
In each of these instances, the economic concept that
determines the price the singer, actor or professional athlete receives is what
Economists term, “marginal revenue product.”
This is fancy economist’s lingo for the revenue that a worker
generated. When boiled down to its
basics, it's no different that the value added by the grocery clerk who rings
you up at the front counter, the kid that mows your yard or the fast food chef
who makes your hamburger. Each worker
adds value to their employer’s final product.
Labor economists typically presume that most labor markets are
competitive. In other words, the supply
of labor comes from a pool of workers that is so large that workers are willing
to work at whatever the prevailing wage is.
Graphically, this means that the labor supply curve is upward sloping
because extra workers (or existing workers on the clock) must be paid more to
induce them to work more hours.
The demand for labor comes from what firms are willing to pay and
that reflects the marginal revenue product of labor. Graphically, this means the typical demand
curve is downward sloping because of the
law of diminishing marginal returns
which states that as more labor is employed into a fixed amount of capital, that
labor’s productivity diminishes and thus employers will pay more for these
additional units of labor only if they are discounted to reflect this decline
in productivity.
How does this apply to professional athletes or college
athletes? Well, it doesn’t and that is
the problem. Most laymen and quite frankly, the NCAA view student athletes as
laborers coming from a large pool. In many cases that is true and
if you look at all NCAA member schools and all the NCAA athletes for all the
schools, that is true. Because this perspective is fallacious just as putting Lebron James in the same pool of all people who play basketball is fallacious. Thus, the NCAA views the back up catcher on
the last place Division II women’s softball team having the same revenue production as the Heisman trophy winner. While both people are student-athletes and both are probably hard working Americans, they do not produce revenue for their schools at the same rate.
Valuing the worth of an athlete is a tough endeavor. In professional sports, professional teams struggle with how much
to pay players. The periodic labor
disputes in the NBA, MLB and NFL attest to this. The elaborate tap dance that occurs after
each NBA, MLB or NFL draft of new players also shows that teams are unsure on
what the value of a new player is.
Obviously it is very difficult to measure future productivity because the prediction of the future is a sum of past experiences.
At the collegiate level this is even more pronounced. After all, the players are often a few months
out of high school. Their performance
on the field can be affected by a myriad of personal pressures such as
girlfriends, boyfriends, family, classes, car problems, side jobs, peer pressure and the list goes
on. So how should a university value
the performance of a player for a season or a game or a college career?
Or for that matter, does it have any value?
If it is difficult to value, does that mean the player should
receive nothing in return?
In the next few blogs, I will explain the Hamilton Plan
which is a plan for NCAA athletes to be paid in the currency of scholarship
vouchers which they may sell, transfer or trade as they please. In many ways, this plan is a throwback to the old school notion that a student should be compensated with an education and that academia and sports should be woven closer together, not separated.
The end result of this plan is that not only would players receive monetary compensation, but those colleges and universities that provide the best academics will be rewarded for providing a superior education. Thus, those smaller mid-major universities are elevated to the same level playing field as the big universities with mega donors in their alumni.
The end result of this plan is that not only would players receive monetary compensation, but those colleges and universities that provide the best academics will be rewarded for providing a superior education. Thus, those smaller mid-major universities are elevated to the same level playing field as the big universities with mega donors in their alumni.
Comments